The Scared Worker. By Robert J. Samuelson.
The Scared Worker. By Robert J. Samuelson. Real Clear Politics, September 2, 2013. Also at the Washington Post.
Tours of Duty: The New Employer-Employee Contract. By Reid Hoffman, Ben Casnocha, and Chris Yeh. Harvard Business Review, June 2013.
Samuelson:
On this
Labor Day, American workers face a buyers’ market. Employers have the upper
hand and, given today’s languid pace of hiring, the advantage shows few signs
of ending. What looms, at best, is a sluggish descent from high unemployment
(7.4 percent in July) and a prolonged period of stagnant or slow-growing wages. Since 2007,
there has been no gain in average inflation-adjusted wages and total compensation, including fringes, notes the Economic Policy Institute, a liberal
think tank.
The
weak job market has a semi-permanence unlike anything seen since World War II,
and the effects on public opinion extend beyond the unemployed. “People’s
expectations have been really ratcheted down for what they can expect for
themselves and their children,” says EPI economist Lawrence Mishel. There’s a
sense “that the economy just doesn’t produce good jobs anymore.” Possible job
loss becomes more threatening because finding a new job is harder. Says Paul
Taylor of the Pew Research Center: “Security is valued more than money because
it’s so fragile.”
What’s
occurring is the final breakdown of the post-World War II job compact, with its
promises of career jobs and something close to “full employment.” The
dissolution of these expectations compounds stress and uncertainty.
Over
the past century, we’ve had three broad labor regimes. The first, in the early
1900s, featured “unfettered labor markets,” as economic historian Price Fishback of the University of Arizona puts it. Competition set wages and
working conditions. There was no federal unemployment insurance or union
protection. Workers were fired if they offended bosses or the economy slumped;
they quit if they thought they could do better. Turnover was high: Fewer than a
third of manufacturing workers in 1913 had been at their current jobs for more than five years.
After
World War II, labor relations became more regulated and administered — the
second regime. The Wagner Act of 1935 gave workers the right to organize;
decisions of the National War Labor Board also favored unions. By 1945, unions
represented about a third of private workers, up from 10 percent in 1929.
Health insurance, pensions and job protections proliferated. Factory workers
laid off during recessions could expect to be recalled when the economy
recovered. Job security improved. By 1973, half of manufacturing workers had been at the same job for more than five years.
To
avoid unionization and retain skilled workers, large nonunion companies
emulated these practices. Career jobs were often the norm. If you went to work
for IBM at 25, you could expect to retire from IBM at 65. Fringe benefits expanded. Corporate America, unionized or not, created a private welfare state
to protect millions from job and income loss.
But in
some ways, the guarantees were too rigid and costly. They started to unravel
with the harsh 1981-82 recession (peak monthly unemployment: 10.8 percent). As
time passed, companies faced increasing competition from imports and new
technologies. Pressure mounted from Wall Street for higher profits. In some
industries, labor became uncompetitive. Career jobs slowly vanished as a norm;
managers fired workers to cut costs. Unions provided diminishing protection. In
2012, they represented only 6.6 percent of private workers. Old organized
sectors (steel, autos) have shrunk. New sectors, from high tech to fast food,
have proved hard to organize. Companies have ferociously resisted. (Public unionization is 36 percent, but that’s another story.)
Now
comes the third labor regime: a confusing mix of old and new. The private safety net is shredding, though the public safety net (unemployment insurance,
Social Security, anti-poverty programs, anti-discrimination laws) remains.
Economist Fishback suggests we may be drifting back toward “unfettered labor
markets” with greater personal instability, insecurity — and responsibility.
Workers are often referred to as “free agents.” An article in the Harvard Business Review argues that lifetime employment at one company is dead and
proposes the following compact: Companies invest in workers’ skills to make
them more employable when they inevitably leave; workers reciprocate by
devoting those skills to improving corporate profitability.
“The
new compact isn’t about being nice,” the article says. “It’s based on an
understanding that a company is its talent, that low performers will be cut,
and that the way to attract talent is to offer appealing opportunities.”
Workers
can’t be too picky, because their power has eroded. Another indicator: After
years of stability, labor’s share — in wages and fringes — of non-farm business
income slipped from 63 percent in 2000 to 57 percent in 2013, reports the White House Council of Economic Advisers. But an even greater decline in 22 other
advanced countries, albeit over a longer period, suggests worldwide pressures
on workers. Take your pick: globalization; new labor-saving technologies;
sluggish economies. Workers do best when strong growth and tight markets raise
real wages. On Labor Day 2013, this prospect is nowhere in sight.